Is Share Price Related to Marketability? Evidence from Mutual Fund Share Splits
Although practitioners suggest that marketability is the primary reason for executing a split (e.g., Baker and Gallagher, 1980; Baker and Powell, 1993), few papers have rigorously explored this possibility. However, academic research on common stock splits has found some support for the marketability hypothesis. For example, Lamoureux and Poon (1987) and Maloney and Mulherin (1992) report that the number of shareholders increases following common stock splits. Schultz (1999) shows that the number of small orders increases following a stock split, and that the bulk of these orders are buys. [2] Angel, Brooks, and Mathew (1997) show that trading activity by small investors increases following a stock split. Fernando, Krishnamurthy, and Spindt (1999) show that firms going public appear to use the offering price to influence investor interest in the issue.
According to the trading-range hypothesis, round-lot constraints and transaction cost considerations result in a preferred price level, which is restored by the split. According to the signaling hypothesis, managers implement stock splits to communicate favorable private information about the firm's prospects.
However, these competing explanations do not fit very well the case of mutual fund splits. [3] Existing transaction cost and constraint-driven explanations of a trading range do not apply, since mutual funds do not trade in ticks and any transaction costs or trade size restrictions are not related to share prices. Also, in a recent paper, Rozeff (1998) finds that splitting funds do not subsequently outperform non-splitting funds. Rozeff argues that this result is inconsistent with managerial signaling. Therefore, mutual fund splits provide a relatively clean testing ground for the marketability hypothesis.
The marketability hypothesis states that a splitting fund will attract new money and new shareholders. Rozeff (1998) examines 167 stock splits by mutual funds. He finds no evidence of increased inflow following splits, a finding that appears to contradict the marketability hypothesis. However, Rozeff uses annual data and matches funds based on asset growth in the year the split occurred. This "screen" is coarse and thus might not detect noisy excess inflow that could only occur after the split.
In this paper, we extend Rozeff's work by examining data on 194 stock splits mutual funds executed between 1978 and 1993. We test for excess inflow by using quarterly data, and we control matching funds based on asset growth, performance, and size in the year before the split. We use quarterly data to estimate the timing of any excess inflow more precisely, and we match on prior period characteristics to minimize look-ahead bias in the results.
We find evidence of excess inflow into splitting funds in the quarter of the split and in the two subsequent quarters. The cumulative excess inflow of new money into the splitting funds during the two quarters after the split averages $8.5 million or about 5.6% of net assets.[4] We also find that relative to control funds, there is a significant increase in the number of shareholders in the split year. These findings support the hypothesis that splits improve marketability by restoring share prices to a preferred trading range.
We supplement our empirical work with survey evidence on the views of 52 mutual fund managers. Their responses are also consistent with the marketability hypothesis. These managers generally believe that a lower net asset value (NAV) per share attracts the attention of small investors. Moreover, they do not believe that mutual fund splits convey favorable information about future fund performance.
Conventional justifications of a preferred trading range do not explain why investors respond favorably to mutual fund splits. Although we cannot rule out some as-yet-undiscovered rational explanation for investors' positive response to splits, there may be behavioral (e.g., herding, as in Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch, 1992) or cognitive (e.g., framing, as in Thaler, 1985) factors that lead investors to prefer a trading range. If behavioral or cognitive factors can explain mutual fund splits, they might also be able to explain common stock splits. Indeed, the rationale provided by our findings for why fund managers undertake splits is strikingly similar to the rationale corporate managers cite for undertaking splits of common stock.
Thus, behavioral or cognitive factors could also give rise to a preferred trading range. If so, managers would undertake splits in recognition of these factors to enhance the marketability of their funds. If the marketability hypothesis holds, we would expect managers to set post-split prices close to industry averages and for splits to attract new money and investors.
We selected all open-end mutual funds identified in the CDA Weisenberger Investment Companies Yearbook as executing a split during the period 1978 to 1993. [10] We also searched the CDA Weisenberger Mutual Funds Update from 1982 to 1993, the mutual funds section of the Nasdaq OTC Daily Stock Price Record from 1981 to 1993, and the Moody's Dividend Record and the S&P Dividend Record, both from 1978 to 1993 for additional splitting funds.
Our final sample consists of 194 mutual funds that executed a split during the 1978 to 1993 period. Approximately 1% of all mutual funds split in a given year during this period.
Although practitioners suggest that marketability is the primary reason for executing a split (e.g., Baker and Gallagher, 1980; Baker and Powell, 1993), few papers have rigorously explored this possibility. However, academic research on common stock splits has found some support for the marketability hypothesis. For example, Lamoureux and Poon (1987) and Maloney and Mulherin (1992) report that the number of shareholders increases following common stock splits. Schultz (1999) shows that the number of small orders increases following a stock split, and that the bulk of these orders are buys. [2] Angel, Brooks, and Mathew (1997) show that trading activity by small investors increases following a stock split. Fernando, Krishnamurthy, and Spindt (1999) show that firms going public appear to use the offering price to influence investor interest in the issue.
According to the trading-range hypothesis, round-lot constraints and transaction cost considerations result in a preferred price level, which is restored by the split. According to the signaling hypothesis, managers implement stock splits to communicate favorable private information about the firm's prospects.
However, these competing explanations do not fit very well the case of mutual fund splits. [3] Existing transaction cost and constraint-driven explanations of a trading range do not apply, since mutual funds do not trade in ticks and any transaction costs or trade size restrictions are not related to share prices. Also, in a recent paper, Rozeff (1998) finds that splitting funds do not subsequently outperform non-splitting funds. Rozeff argues that this result is inconsistent with managerial signaling. Therefore, mutual fund splits provide a relatively clean testing ground for the marketability hypothesis.
The marketability hypothesis states that a splitting fund will attract new money and new shareholders. Rozeff (1998) examines 167 stock splits by mutual funds. He finds no evidence of increased inflow following splits, a finding that appears to contradict the marketability hypothesis. However, Rozeff uses annual data and matches funds based on asset growth in the year the split occurred. This "screen" is coarse and thus might not detect noisy excess inflow that could only occur after the split.
In this paper, we extend Rozeff's work by examining data on 194 stock splits mutual funds executed between 1978 and 1993. We test for excess inflow by using quarterly data, and we control matching funds based on asset growth, performance, and size in the year before the split. We use quarterly data to estimate the timing of any excess inflow more precisely, and we match on prior period characteristics to minimize look-ahead bias in the results.
We find evidence of excess inflow into splitting funds in the quarter of the split and in the two subsequent quarters. The cumulative excess inflow of new money into the splitting funds during the two quarters after the split averages $8.5 million or about 5.6% of net assets.[4] We also find that relative to control funds, there is a significant increase in the number of shareholders in the split year. These findings support the hypothesis that splits improve marketability by restoring share prices to a preferred trading range.
We supplement our empirical work with survey evidence on the views of 52 mutual fund managers. Their responses are also consistent with the marketability hypothesis. These managers generally believe that a lower net asset value (NAV) per share attracts the attention of small investors. Moreover, they do not believe that mutual fund splits convey favorable information about future fund performance.
Conventional justifications of a preferred trading range do not explain why investors respond favorably to mutual fund splits. Although we cannot rule out some as-yet-undiscovered rational explanation for investors' positive response to splits, there may be behavioral (e.g., herding, as in Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch, 1992) or cognitive (e.g., framing, as in Thaler, 1985) factors that lead investors to prefer a trading range. If behavioral or cognitive factors can explain mutual fund splits, they might also be able to explain common stock splits. Indeed, the rationale provided by our findings for why fund managers undertake splits is strikingly similar to the rationale corporate managers cite for undertaking splits of common stock.
Thus, behavioral or cognitive factors could also give rise to a preferred trading range. If so, managers would undertake splits in recognition of these factors to enhance the marketability of their funds. If the marketability hypothesis holds, we would expect managers to set post-split prices close to industry averages and for splits to attract new money and investors.
We selected all open-end mutual funds identified in the CDA Weisenberger Investment Companies Yearbook as executing a split during the period 1978 to 1993. [10] We also searched the CDA Weisenberger Mutual Funds Update from 1982 to 1993, the mutual funds section of the Nasdaq OTC Daily Stock Price Record from 1981 to 1993, and the Moody's Dividend Record and the S&P Dividend Record, both from 1978 to 1993 for additional splitting funds.
Our final sample consists of 194 mutual funds that executed a split during the 1978 to 1993 period. Approximately 1% of all mutual funds split in a given year during this period.